Credit: Zerbor, Getty Images
In his column earlier this week, ‘From Jeremy Corbyn to Bernie Sanders to Elizabeth Warren; what the Left is getting right’, Liam Halligan highlighted Jeremy Corbyn’s focus on housing and Democrat Senator Elizabeth Warren’s call for banking reform as examples of ‘what the Left gets right’. In her column Charlie Pickles adds the minimum wage and capital spending to that list.
***
UnHerd has been exploring the global march of the Left.
Think Iglesias in Spain, Tsipras in Greece, Melenchon in France, and Corbyn and Sanders in the UK and US. Some have established new parties, others have radicalised old ones. Either way, in capturing the popular imagination, these socialist candidates have helped shake up mainstream political parties which had become overly comfortable in their grip on power. The financial crash â with its big bank bail outs and years of austerity â created a sense that âtraditionalâ parties and politicians just werenât serving the people. That the rich have largely recovered their pre-crash wealth while lower and middle-income families continue to struggle appears to prove the point.1
Itâs easy to dismiss the populist positions espoused by the hard-Left (and from the hard-Right, too, who uncannily often promote the exact same populisms). And certainly, basic economics shows that some of the policies put forward â from protectionism to huge, unfunded increases in public spending â would end up hurting the very people they are supposed to help. It is lazily partisan to reject their platforms entirely, however.
So, further to Liam Halligan’s “What the Left gets right” column, here are two other policies that sensible people should get behind.
First⌠minimum wages DO need to rise
âMillions of Americans are working for totally inadequate wages. We must ensure that no full-time worker lives in poverty. The current federal minimum wage is starvation pay and must become a living wage. We must increase it to $15 an hour over the next several years.â2
There is undoubtedly merit in Bernie Sanderâs argument, which has clearly been recognised by the 19 US states that, with varying levels of generosity, raised their minimum wages at the start of this year3 – a mixture of both Democrat and Republican. In Britain, George Osborne, the Chancellor in a Conservative government, legislated for what he called the National Living Wage in 2015.

Across advanced, capitalist economies, the share of wealth going to labour has decreased. As Ryan Avent highlights in his book The Wealth of Humans:4
â[In America] Prior to the early 1970s⌠as workers got better at generating output, the fruits of those improvements accrued to the workers themselves, in the form of higher pay. Thereafter productivity growth slowed and workers failed even to capture the benefits of that slower growth; from 2005 to 2014, for instance, productivity grew at about 1.4 per cent per year, or about twice as fast as growth in real wages.â
In fact, as Avent goes on to say, the use of averages masks an even worse reality â instead, using median wages, âsince 2000 the real wage for the typical American has not risen at allâ, and âfrom 1995 to 2012, the average real wage in Germany, Italy and Japan all underperformed that in Americaâ. At the extreme, between 2011 and 2013, Greece saw three consecutive years of 10% reductions in total gross wages.5
Productivity gains are increasingly going to the owners of capital (exacerbating income inequality). Around half of the decline in the labour share (i.e. that going to workers) can be explained by automation, and a further quarter by globalisation (especially the offshoring of jobs).6 While this makes sense, rational explanations, of course, do nothing for the low and middle earners struggling to make ends meet and turning to the politicians promising a pay rise. And many of the (typically big) businesses reaping the benefits of technology and globalisation could afford to give one.
Critics of minimum wage hikes will shout about job losses. Indeed, the UK Office for Budget Responsibility â tasked with providing independent scrutiny and forecasts for the public finances â predicted 60,000 job losses as a result of 2015’s National Living Wage. It will be some time before we can assess the accuracy of that projection, but several studies looking at the impact over time challenge this common pessimism. One study of US federal minimum wage increases between 1938 and 2009 found that:7
âBasic economic indicators show no correlation between federal minimum-wage increases and lower employment levels, even in the industries that are most impacted by higher minimum wages. To the contrary, in the substantial majority of instances (68 percent) overall employment increased after a federal minimum-wage increase. In the most substantially affected industries, the rates were even higherâ.
This is in line with UK evidence that minimum wage rises since 1999 have had no negative employment effects on the overall labour market (though part-time workers do seem to have been impacted, which deserves attention).8
More generally, where there is evidence of a negative impact on jobs, it invariably focuses on the lowest skilled, and in particular low-skilled young people.9 That is why any pay-rise for those on the lowest wages should be accompanied by a much greater focus on up-skilling, something which businesses have failed to invest in (unsurprisingly given the abundance of cheap labour). A recent report by think tank IPPR found English businesses are spending ÂŁ5 billion less on training, in real terms, than a decade ago; and spend per employee per year is half that of the European average.10 The risk to youth employment posed by increasing the minimum wage is also why pay levels staggered by age are important (in the UK, the rate for under-18s is almost half that for over 25s), and why training schemes such apprenticeships that provide a partial wage are key.
Of course, while a pay-rise is a worthy (even essential) policy in the short to medium-term, the longer-term challenge is preparing the labour force for an era of robots and algorithms. As my colleague Nigel Cameron highlights in a recent piece on the rise of robots, we just donât know what the employment impact is going to be, but we do know the future world of work is going to require different skills (ones Nigel sees as more suited to women). Which is another reason for politicians of all stripes to prioritise not just fair wages, but the skills that will equip workers to earn them.
Second⌠BIG infrastructure investment is essential
Big spending promises are at the heart of the platforms put forward by the Left. And while extravagant general increases in public spending â pushing more and more debt on to younger generations â is poor policy and fiscally dangerous, there is one area in which they are bang on the money: infrastructure spending. Well, let me caveat that, big spending on the right infrastructure under the right circumstances (more on that later).
Bernie Sandersâ 2016 presidential campaign pledged $1 trillion of investment over five years via his âRebuild America Actâ â promising to upgrade everything from bridges and railways, to electricity and broadband.11 In the UK, Labourâs 2017 manifesto included a ÂŁ250 billion âNational Transformation Fundâ to invest in infrastructure projects over ten years, including rail, housing and energy.12
Itâs a form of investing to save â or at least investing to stimulate. Infrastructure is âpillar twoâ of the World Economic Forumâs Global Competitiveness Index, one of four âbasic requirementsâ for a competitive economy. The US ranks third overall for competitiveness, but is outside the top ten at number 11 for infrastructure. The UK is seventh overall, but ninth for infrastructure â and it ranks just 27th for roads and 19th for rail.13
For Sanders and Corbyn, however, pledges of serious spending for infrastructure renewal are couched in a more fundamental truth: the building blocks of economic success matter on a human level. As Harvard Business School Professor Rosabeth Moss Kanter puts it in relation to transport:14
âThe state of transportation infrastructure touches every important societal issue: health and safety, air quality, family budgets, productivity and use of time, inequality and social mobility, the nature of cities, jobs for today and jobs for the future. Public transportation in particular, I found, is an important ride out of poverty and into the middle class if it provides access to jobs and education.
Once America was the worldâs acknowledged innovator. Now weâre stuck on the way to the futureâstuck in traffic, stuck in congressional gridlock, and stuck in history.âÂ
One Harvard study found lower commuter time is a strong factor in low-income families escaping poverty and achieving upward mobility.15 Which when you think about it, is not that surprising: employment is the best route out of poverty, but you have to be able to get to work. Common sense.

Crucially though, back to my caveat, not all spending is equal â or even good. Over-runs in time and budget are common in public projects (the UKâs high speed rail project HS2, for example, was reported to be ÂŁ7 billion over budget in 201616), wasting taxpayer funds. But as Tyler Duvall â a former under secretary for policy at the US Department of Transportation â argued in 2010, the greatest waste comes from the failure to act strategically:17
âPut simply, a business starts by asking the question: âWhat will the project achieve for us?â The company then compares the expected return on the project’s investment with other potential uses of capital â treating the company’s available funds as fungible across a wide array of investment opportunities, and estimating the benefits of alternative projects in order to ensure the best use of a limited budget. Once a project is undertaken, a post-investment assessment is conducted to determine whether it was a success, and whether the returns on investment met the company’s expectations. The results of the review then shape decisions about future investments. The private-sector approach is hardly rocket science: It requires simply prioritizing needs, investing in the projects that will yield the most benefit and value, and keeping track of what works and what doesnât.â
Again, common sense. It also means, as Duvall points out, considering that the best approach might not create the best photo-op. Congestion charges and market pricing, for example, enable more efficient use of existing transport capacity, but donât generate the âlocal investmentâ headlines of pork barrel projects. The difference is, they actually deliver value: in 2005, to deal with congestion, differential pricing (based on peak and off-peak times) was introduced at the ports of Los Angeles and Long Beach, within two months around a third of shipping traffic was shifted to off peak.18
Likewise, the political bias is often towards a shiny new, ribbon-cutting opportunity rather than the essential upgrade of crumbling infrastructure. Yet, as a paper by Brookings argues: “Itâs easier to allocate maintenance money efficiently than money for new projects.”19
Big investment is needed, but, as is invariably the case with public spending, itâs how you spend it.
(Steve Hilton Discusses the populism sweeping many Western economies, and his belief that it can be converted into a positive agenda for a change.)
The policies of the Left are imbued with a sense of hope and a promise of change
Both these policies have clear, tangible benefits to peopleâs lives. They are not abstract arguments about debt and deficit (as important as those are); they are about giving not taking, in the form of a hand up not a hand out. They are, ultimately, a promise of a better standard of living. And that, perhaps, is the most compelling part of the Leftâs platform. They offer hope. In his essay for UnHerd last week, Angus Robertson, Deputy Leader of the Scottish National Party, argued that:
âIn Greece and Spain, Syriza and Podemos ran on a âhope agendaâ that things can and must be better for society, something that resonated especially for many young voters in countries with mammoth levels of youth unemployment.â
Pablo Iglesias, Secretary-General of Spainâs Podemos party, says âwe saw ourselves as a force for renewalâ, which in an era of stagnation for many is compelling.20
In an interview with UnHerd, Steve Hilton, former adviser to UK Prime Minister David Cameron and current Fox talk show host, advocated âpositive populismâ. Hilton sees in the populism sweeping the West a chance to turn âit into an agenda for real reform and for change, that actually ends up really improving the daily lives of people.â If mainstream politicians are to compete, if the centre is to regain ground, then it is âpositive populismâ they must embrace. They could do worse than starting with policies that increase low wages and create opportunity.
***
FURTHER READING
For a discussion, and evidence review, of the decline in labour share see Silvia Merler, âThe decline of the labour share of incomeâ, Bruegel, 24 April 2017
Klaus Schwab, âThe Global Competitiveness Report 2016-17â, World Economic Forum, 2016
Tyler Duvall, âUnclogging Transportationâ, National Affairs, Spring 2010
Join the discussion
Join like minded readers that support our journalism by becoming a paid subscriber
To join the discussion in the comments, become a paid subscriber.
Join like minded readers that support our journalism, read unlimited articles and enjoy other subscriber-only benefits.
Subscribe