Or take air travel. As an island nation we could have built our airports on the coast so that aircraft descend and ascend over water, not people. We could have balanced the right to see the world against the right to tranquility at home. We could make the aviation industry pay for what it’s doing to the planet — instead we subsidise it.
And it’s not just transport. In every aspect of modern life, we meekly accept the hammer blows of progress. Consider construction, for instance. We’ve never been in a better position to build beautiful, brilliantly designed buildings that stand the test of time. We have machinery and materials that would amaze our ancestors. We also have the necessary knowledge. The sum total of humanity’s architectural achievement is available at the click of a button. We have armies of architects, designers and planners — and ways of drawing upon the experience and insights of local residents. Always and everywhere, development could make places better.
But instead we just make them bigger, blighting our lives with ugliness and dysfunction as a careless byproduct. We can’t even make our modern dystopias interesting anymore, the insults of brutalism replaced by spreadsheet architecture.
I could go on. In just about any field of economic activity — from agriculture to information technology — it seems that we can’t create without also destroying. Things that aren’t priced by market mechanisms, but which have value nonetheless — from local wildlife to the decentralised flow of information — are lost to us forever.
Is this just the price of progress? We can either have birds tweeting in the trees or shops full of food, but not both. Nature or abundance. Tranquility or mobility. Community or convenience. Localism or variety. That, supposedly, is the choice.
But, of course, it isn’t. As I’ve tried to show above, we can deploy our technologies with care. We can think through the consequences, correct our mistakes, direct our efforts away from danger, choose one path over another. For example, the UK has put decades of effort into making our roads safer. Our fatality rate is significantly lower than in Germany or France, it’s half the Canadian rate and a quarter of America’s. We should be proud.
*
We can design a better world if we want it. So why don’t we do it more often and to a greater extent?
Fundamentally, it’s because it means constraining the most dynamic forces in our economy: speed, energy, extraction, transportation, production, consumption, demolition, construction, automation, immigration, globalisation, finance.
These are destructive forces, but they’re also creative. Try to tame them, and the risk is that we will slow down or even kill the essence of life, which is growth.
The case for growth is a powerful one. Nobody makes it better than the economist Tyler Cowen in his book Stubborn Attachments. While a lot of attention is paid to the GDP growth rate at any particular time, Cowen argues that we overlook the importance of growth as it multiplies over decades and centuries. Seemingly small differences in average growth rates can compound into radically different outcomes several generations down the line.
Accepting a less dynamic, slower economy now would mean that our great, great, great grandchildren will live in a much poorer world than they otherwise would have done. And if you’re wondering why we should care about descendants we’ll never meet, consider how you’d feel about our ancestors if they’d taken the same attitude. If, say, they’d suppressed the industrial revolution as being too disruptive of their way of life, we’d now be living in abject poverty. Never mind the temporary shutdown we’re living through now, the modern economy as we understand it wouldn’t exist at all — nor would it for generations to come.
Therefore, within his consequentialist moral framework Cowen believes that we have a duty to keep growth going at the maximum sustainable rate. Not being a fool, he realises that economic activities can compromise that sustainability, for instance by messing up the climate. Yet within these basic constraints (and also respect for human rights), the argument is that growth is the greatest of greater goods.
What does such a worldview imply? Certainly that we should accept a little global dimming so that aviation can connect a global economy. As for pollution, then yes, within limits, it’s worth putting up with. Our paleolithic ancestors enjoyed unpolluted air, untainted water, got plenty of exercise, ate organic low carb food … and were all dead by the age of 40. I mean, would you swap with a caveman? As for too little wildlife, would you rather have too much (again, ask the cavemen)?
Further implications are that traffic accidents are a price worth paying for mobility. Lousy architecture is the price we pay for urbanisation — and a rate of development that allows countries like China to lift their people out of rural poverty. Of course, we in the West wouldn’t tolerate Chinese environmental standards, but then that stage in our development is safely in the past.
*
So, then, an overwhelming case for letting the economy rip — decarbonising as we must, but otherwise allowing the forces of growth to find the path of least resistance?
Here are three reasons why not:
The first is that some components of growth are worth a lot more than others. The most important is technological progress. Over time, it is all that matters to an economy (beyond people, of course, and the availability of natural resources). It can be amplified by other forces — like prudent finance and capable government — but ultimately, growth relies on innovation. Take that away and growth eventually stops — though it can run for a while on fumes (e.g. the debt-fuelled property speculation that is recorded as ‘growth’ in our flawed GDP statistics).
We use the word ‘breakthrough’ to describe instances of scientific or technological progress because discovery is difficult. A growth strategy based on always allowing economic activity to find the path of least resistance is therefore counter-productive. Innovation depends on resources being directed at the right challenges (the paths of fruitful resistance, if you will) and overcoming them. Necessity, not deregulation, is the mother of invention.
Secondly, growth is not the only thing that makes an enormous difference on a generational timescale. We also have to be aware of extremely unlikely but highly consequential risks — Black Swan risks. Any long-run economic calculus of the sort that Tyler Cowen advocates has to take account of the fact that the highly improbable becomes increasingly certain given enough time.
Now, those risks may be external to a high-growth economic model — like nuclear war. Or they may be intrinsic, but adjustable — like averting the dangers of climate change by switching to clean energy sources. But what if the black swan risks arise out of, or are greatly multiplied by, something that is an integral feature of our favoured economic model?
The obvious example, right now, is infectious disease in the context of globalisation. A hyper-connected world may well be the best way to maximise overall economic growth — until, that is, we’re ruined by our exposure to the food safety practices of other nations. It’s all very well bequeathing future generations the legacy of decades or centuries of high growth, but it won’t help them if they’re all dead.
Finally, we need to ask whether the pro-growth policies that delivered growth in the past are still capable of delivering growth now and in the future. Quite frankly, the record of the neoliberal era isn’t great. Or rather it’s been great for the developing countries — thanks to all that previously invented, off-the-shelf technology waiting to made use of — but not so great for the already developed world.
Western economies have failed to maintain the rapid economic growth and social progress of the three or four decades after the Second World War. We are, to quote the title of another Tyler Cowen book, stuck in a Great Stagnation.
How do we get unstuck? Is it by flogging the dead horse of neoliberalism even harder? More deregulation, more globalisation, more inequality? New roads, airports, skyscrapers: More! More! More! Or, at some point, do we need to stand back and question the fundamentals of what we’re doing?
*
Eric Weinstein likens our efforts to recreate the conditions for rapid growth to a cargo cult. Having experienced a great bounty at one point in our history, we ritualistically go through the motions of this or that pro-growth policy not understanding that it’s not in our power to conjure it up again.
Indeed, the rituals — involving, as they do, great sacrifice — are doing us more harm than good.
Join the discussion
Join like minded readers that support our journalism by becoming a paid subscriber
To join the discussion in the comments, become a paid subscriber.
Join like minded readers that support our journalism, read unlimited articles and enjoy other subscriber-only benefits.
Subscribe“Real wealth increases consumption, shifting the IS curve out to the right, thus pushing up interest rates and increasing aggregate demand. A decrease in real wealth does the opposite.” This is the basis of the Pigou effect or a a real measure of improvement of wealth for the middle class. Sound familiar, it should this has been the OECD annual report for 2 decades. And the trend has been pushing interest rates down, which means real wealth has been in decline while GDP has increased substancially.
This writer is a fool. Sorry to be harsh. His rubbish comments about capitalism. Shows me he doesn’t understand how money is made. He doesn’t understand GDP growth is not connected to real wealth. Printing money is not an answer to improvement in middle income wealth. What is needed is productivity increase per capita. This creates real wealth. GDP growth is soft money which is harvested by George Soros and globalists. Then you have far left Corbyn supporters trying to convince everyone to double down on the three decades of financial and social engineering failure.
The role of mass immigration is to keep working class people’s wages down.
The role of mass stimulas is to keep working class people poor or poorer substituting real wealth for access to debt.
The role of identity politics is to concerntrate the attention of the masses on infighting instead of focusing on constructive common goals. (Like increase to real wealth increases, which only come from increased productivity per capita)
UK once understood the industrial north (Manufacturing High valuable durable goods) was the engine to middle class real wealth gains. Then it forgot??
A cancer was planted into the Labour Party when they sent their kids to university. They thought they would come back enlightened. Instead they came back indoctrinated into the Neo-Liberal SJW Marxist Cult.
Now we all suffer these fools.
“Necessity, not deregulation, is the mother of invention.” Good point – I like that.
Is the growth always a good thing? When cells in a body continually grow without finding balance, we call that cancer…and it kills. Growth can be necessary, but we should not treat it as some kind of utopia that doesn’t also have a dark side when there is too much of it.
I’m not convinced about the dangers of CO2 but well said.
I couldn’t help but notice the similarity in thinking with the late, great, Sir Roger Scruton; his philosophy of conservatism:
The value of the family, the local and the beautiful and the inter-generational obligations between the dead, the living and the unborn. Yes!
What do you mean “we”, Kemosabe? “We” already have the world”airplanes, automobiles, all the mod cons”that most of us want. You want to return to the 18th century. Fine. That’s your business. You can surely find places in North America that fit your specs. I’ve seen enough of the UK to know that there are places there that should suit you. b****r off, then, Your Lordship, and leave the rest if us to our dim, polluted modern world.
The author appears to be considerably ignorant of the extensive criticism of the fallacy that growth = increasing prosperity, and the fact that GDP is nothing remotely like a measure of economic or life-quality good. Very much on the contrary.
And all this “we” “we” “we” “we”. Speak for yourself Sir, you certainly don’t speak for me. I (and numerous others) have been fervently opposing the greed-globalist-driven “growth” for decades, and calling for the past 25 years for the by far most evil invention in history, cars, to be banned until proven safe. Everywhere that cars go, they ruin everything, not least civilised local communities.