It is “easier for a camel to go through the eye of a needle”, the Bible tells us, “than for a rich man to enter into the kingdom of God”. Riches, according to the Church, were associated with sin, and spiritual goals would be enough to ensure that the fruits of God’s earth would provide for the fruits of the loins. And as the market economy developed, creating our modern day capitalism, charity became the means by which merchants and bankers paid for their sins – with the Church keeping us all in check.
Today, with the dark side of capitalism once again on display in vast wealth inequality, stagnating wages and cronyism, we are again associating money with immorality. As a result, Marxist thinking is on the rise and, so too, it seems, are the anti-capitalist pronouncements of the Church. But to reject capitalism as immoral is a mistake.
It was the 18th century political economists David Hume and Adam Smith who turned the idea of the immorality of markets on its head. Hume argued that without the desire to acquire ever greater riches, we would be idle.1 In pondering how economies developed from hunting and gathering to factories, offices and new technologies, Smith suggested that the market harnesses selfishness and channels it in a direction that works in the best interests of society. The natural harmony of the market would translate individual desires into a wider social good. In his own words, “it is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest”.
Smith also believed in the power of the market beyond its money-making power. His Theory of Moral Sentiments placed individuals in the context of a wider society, and brought morality to bear on self-interest. He saw the pursuit of individual life ambitions, not the maximisation of riches, as the key goal in life.
By using the market, he argued, we can more easily and cheaply meet our material needs, but that would also leave more time and resources for us to fulfil whatever non-material goals we may have. Rather than the Church imposing its own view of what our goal should be in life, Smith believed we should answer to our inner selves – to an “impartial spectator” that sits inside each one of us. That is the freedom markets provide, and why accusations of immorality are misplaced.
Here are four reasons why a defence of markets is a defence of much more than money.
Join the discussion
Join like minded readers that support our journalism by becoming a paid subscriber
To join the discussion in the comments, become a paid subscriber.
Join like minded readers that support our journalism, read unlimited articles and enjoy other subscriber-only benefits.
SubscribeAlthough the authoress makes sporadic references to competition, she basically ignores the fact that markets are prone to develop spontaneous defects know in the economic literature as market failures that prevent attainment of optimal social wellbeing, and that these market failures, unless corrected in timely fashion, produce injustice and exploitation. Adam Smith himself mentioned the need for competition, but it was not until the 1930s that Joan Robinson and others systematically developed the theory of monopolies as one of the crucial defects of markets that enabled monopolists to exploit both consumers and non-monopolistic capitalists. Since then many additional market failures have been discovered, such as asymmetrical information and others. In order to confront these market failures, markets must be constantly invigilated and policed by government in order to correct failures as they develop. This was the central concept of so-called Ordoliberalism developed by Walter Eucken, which originally guided the policy of the German government but has long since ceased to do so.
Contrary to Friedrich Hayek’s claims of “spontaneous order”, markets require constant tinkering by supervisory state bodies in order to function properly.