'Growth is about the future. Reeves is focused on the past.' Dan Kitwood / Getty
In 2018, in a pamphlet titled “The Everyday Economy”, a backbench Labour MP called Rachel Reeves attempted to untangle Britain’s convoluted financial system. To do so, she started by drawing upon the history of political philosophy — and the work of one philosopher in particular: David Hume, whom she grandly called “perhaps the most significant figure in the British Enlightenment”.
She didn’t mention another of the UK’s most celebrated political theorists, John Locke. Perhaps she should have read more widely. Indeed, some seven years on, as the now-Chancellor finds herself scrambling to reboot her plan for Britain, it’s Locke’s work on the economy that should be front of mind.
Much more than an academic, Locke was active in the rough and tumble of British politics. It was in the course of his political jostling during the coinage crisis of the late 17th century that he made his most influential arguments on the political nature of money. He recognised that the value of a state’s currency is ultimately set by fiat, and thus within the political power of the sovereign. The sovereign, after all, could alter the worth of the nation’s currency at the drop of a hat — a particularly devastating scenario given the fragility of the money system, which relies on the confidence of the populace. Should the sovereign decide to start altering the value of the currency indiscriminately, that confidence would erode. The whole monetary system, in other words, would fall apart.
To prevent this, Locke suggested that the sovereign refrain from using their political power over money. Instead, to ensure stability, he proposed that the sovereign maintain a fixed value of the currency — not because of any inherent worth of the coinage, as measured by precious metals, but because Locke thought that maintaining a consistent valuation would suggest as much. His plan, as Stefan Eich has observed, “was a political strategy to depoliticise money’s appearance”, making it seem as if the sovereign lacked the power to alter the value of money at any moment and for any reason.
In recent decades most contemporary states have followed Locke’s example, if not fixing the value of their currency in gold, then depoliticising it by putting it under the purview of an independent central bank. Then came Liz Truss, who in her campaign for the leadership of the Conservative Party began to question the independence of the Bank of England, and in the wake of her failed premiership blamed her fortunes on the Bank. The supposed neutrality of Britain’s monetary policy suddenly risked being exposed.
Labour subsequently attempted to put as much space between them and Truss’s questioning of economic policymaking practices as possible. Under the watchful eye of Reeves, the Government ran back into the arms of the BoE and the OBR, reinforcing its commitment to “sensible” economic policy, by which it meant depoliticised policy conducted by “sensible” experts. The storm, apparently, had passed.
But is the stasis we’re in any better? As the past fortnight’s U-turns have demonstrated, the Labour government finds itself hamstrung, unable to engage in transformative politics and susceptible to political challenge from the Right. We could be forgiven for asking: will that ever change? Or perhaps more importantly, would the storm really be worse?
Let’s start at the beginning. The conventional economic theory of money is rooted in a potted history of its use. That history goes roughly like this: before money, people bartered. They traded goods and services for each other. Bartering, however, proved inefficient, as each trade required a “double coincidence of wants” — I have to want exactly what you have, and you have to want exactly what I have. Money solves this problem. If everyone wants money, as a medium of exchange, there is no need to satisfy the “double coincidence”, as money ensures it is always satisfied.
There are (at least) two problems with this story. First, it is historically inaccurate. As far as economic historians and sociologists are concerned, there never was an exclusively barter economy. Money in the form of credit (and debt) has always existed. It was never the case that, as a table-maker, I would need to barter with each individual to get all the resources necessary to build tables; rather, it was more likely that the blacksmith had a ledger in which he recorded my debts each time I needed nails. Then someday, I might repay those with a table. Those ledgers, or more precisely the credit they recorded, was a form of money, a solution to the (never actually experienced) problem of the “double coincidence of wants”.
The second problem with the bartering story is the implication that money has no effect on production. Put simply, money makes trade easier. It does not change what resources exist, nor what technologies are available, nor how much labour is free. From this perspective, money has no influence on what could be produced in the economy. It simply makes trade, and therefore production, more efficient. And there’s nothing political about that. In economics this is known as monetary neutrality. Because money doesn’t go into building things or delivering services — there are no pound coins in your coffee or notes used in the construction of your home — it is merely a veil on the economy; without it the same things could be produced and created, albeit less efficiently.
The idea that money is nothing more than a veil on the real economy goes back at least to Hume’s essay on the balance of trade, in which he argued against mercantilist trade policies. (This essay did not feature in Reeves’s pamphlet.) Free-trade policies, he suggested, are the most desirable, because what matters to a nation’s economy is not its stock of money but rather its stock of goods and services — or perhaps more accurately, its capacity to produce real goods and services. Consequently, it does not make sense to stockpile gold and other forms of money as the mercantilists advocate. Instead, Hume argued, nations should “preserve money nearly proportionable to the art and industry of each nation”. Like Milton Friedman after him, Hume suggested that the role of good monetary policy was to ensure the supply of money matches the real economy.
But what this fails to take account of is the temporal dimension of production. It may be true that, without money, all the same production could take place, in the sense that the economic fundamentals are unchanged. But without money, the same amount of production would not in fact take place. From a realistic point of view, the efficiency and convenience that money introduces into the economic system inevitably affects what can be produced, where, and how much, in a given period of time.
Nevertheless, the theory of monetary neutrality is widely accepted, as is its corollary: if money is neutral, then so is monetary policy. The claim is deceptively simple. On this view, monetary policy governs how much money is in the economy, or the price of money, by managing short-term interest rates. It does not, however, influence the relative prices of goods. Consider the following illustration. Suppose a loaf of bread costs $1 and a gallon of milk costs $5. Now, suppose there is a massive injection of new money into the economy and a loaf of bread now costs $10 and a gallon of milk $50. The relative prices remain the same, so the price increase should have no influence on production. Thus, claim monetary neutrality advocates, monetary policy has no influence on the real economy.
Monetary policymakers, in this view, are like the ball boys and girls at a tennis match. They determine when to throw the balls onto the court or when to inject new money into the economy. If they do their job well, they enable the tennis players to play to the best of their ability, not breaking their flow, and allowing them to produce their best possible game. However, they could make mistakes, releasing lots of balls onto the court, causing the players to trip or get confused, or failing to give the players balls when necessary, causing the game to stop and the players to be unable to play. Getting monetary policy right, just like being a good ball boy, means preventing money from being a source of disturbance. A good ball girl cannot make the players better than they are. Similarly, conventional monetary theory suggests good monetary policy cannot improve real productive possibility. More money does not mean more production, just as more balls do not mean better tennis.
However, it can’t be that monetary policy is completely neutral. After all, if monetary policy has no effect on actual economic production, if it were impotent in relation to the real economy, why would we care about monetary policymaking at all? It simply wouldn’t matter. It would be like gravity policy. The reason monetary policy is not like this is that the neutrality claimed for monetary policy has one crucial qualifier: it is thought to be neutral only in the long run.
Hume recognised this in his essay. He argued that while money would not matter in the long run, in the short run an increase in money could cause a burst in economic activity. Back to the bread and milk. If the central bank were to inject money into the economy, all prices would not automatically adjust in tandem. Rather, it may be the case that the price of a loaf of bread would increase from $1 to $10 before milk went from $5 to $50, supposing it ever does. As such, in the interim, the change in relative prices (bread at $10, milk still at $5), could have a significant impact on the production and consumption of milk and bread. By claiming that monetary policy is neutral in the long run, but not the short run, the conventional view holds that by the time the economy reaches equilibrium, any effects downstream of monetary policy will be neutralised.
Which is all very well — except for the fact that money is not neutral, as we all know. Who has access to money — credit in particular — determines who gets to go to law school, buy a house, expand their business and so on. Conventional economic theorists would respond, well, yes of course this is true in the short run, but in the (theoretical) long run money makes no difference in the aggregate. But this is ridiculous. The person in real life with access to a loan to go to law school then becomes more likely to get a good mortgage because of their law degree. Their house then grows in value, which gives them more access to credit and income which they can invest, which allows them to make more money, and so on. This impacts not just the distribution of income in society but its aggregate productive capacity as well. The effects of short-run access to credit aren’t neutralised in the long run in which we actually live. Far from it.
And yet, despite this, the mainstream Left in both the UK and the US remains grounded in the monetary policy neutrality doctrine. Which brings us back to Reeves. She wants growth for Britain. Her supporters describe her as laser focused on it, her detractors as desperate for it. In any case, she has offered nothing transformational to secure it. Her theory of growth seems to be preventing the Tories from cutting taxes, discussing long-term planning reform (which could actually make a difference, but not anytime soon), and maybe someday building another runway at Heathrow to “make Britain the world’s best connected place to do business”. Oh, and not to do anything to piss off the City. Her theory of growth, in other words, is: let’s go back to the Nineties.
It is not the Nineties. The growth of the Nineties wasn’t built on production, but rather on selling off what Britain had, and now it’s gone. That won’t work again. Growth, like politics, is about the future. Reeves is focused on the past. The Nineties were the age in which Britain embraced monetary neutrality, exemplified by the 1997 decision to make the Bank of England independent. Reeves would do well not to make Locke’s mistake, again. Today, states all over the world have followed Locke in depoliticising money on the basis that, over the long run, monetary policy will have no effect on the real economy. And as many are now discovering, there are two issues with this. First, as we’ve seen, it’s not true. And second, to act as if it is neuters our political capacity.
There is almost nothing more fundamental to a state than its power to create money. We cannot just create money out of nowhere whenever we want for whatever reason and assume there will be no negative consequences. We can, however, just create money, and we have done that a lot in recent decades, to support war, to bail out ailing financial institutions, and to survive pandemics. Even in the face of this, we — and particularly the current British government — seem to have failed to grasp the obvious implication: creating money is a political choice and thus, in a democratic society, when and how the state creates money, and on what basis, should be a democratic decision.
Drawn from ‘Our Money: Monetary Policy as if Democracy Matters’.
Join the discussion
Join like minded readers that support our journalism by becoming a paid subscriber
To join the discussion in the comments, become a paid subscriber.
Join like minded readers that support our journalism, read unlimited articles and enjoy other subscriber-only benefits.
SubscribeInteresting piece: but I would like to know what policies Leah recommends by way of a solution.
Perhaps, but this is an academic critique of Rachel Reeves, so there is no necessity for the author to superimpose her own views on how she would behave differently. In my opinion you see too much of that.
Exactly. One needn’t be able to play a note of the piano one’s self to easily perceive the faults when Les Dawson played a piano piece and hilariously hit wrong notes!
Very interesting.
I’m not convinced though that overt political control over the money supply is ideal.
Absolutely, technical people over estimate their foresight and wisdom but, I suggest, that at the time Brown’s decision was wise. Political control of the money supply, like tax policy was more dependent on the electoral cycle than on the needs of the economy.
As the writer implies, prosperity is only ultimately increased through productivity; we get wealthier because we get better at making stuff. The state’s role in this process in minimal; infrastructure, basic competent education, basic effective health care, functional property rights and some social safety net. Rachel Reeves should not be trying to pick out areas for a new silicon valley, she should just ensure that she doesn’t get in the way of entrepreneurs.
Of course, getting in the way of entrepreneurs is exactly what she’s done.
It didn’t take Brown long to undermine his own decision by changing the criteria under which the BoE sets interest rates in order to trigger a pre-election house price boom. Simultaneously Blair launched his mass immigration policy. The result has been the largest upward transfer of wealth in the country’s history.
Following the catastrophic failure of Reeves’ first budget, Starmer’s government are already talking about relaxing mortgage eligibility criteria in order to do the same.
I have read this essay very carefully and as a simple explanation of Political Economy in the past it is brilliant. As Liam F says, it offers a history of theory but no solution.
However, I don’t really trust analysis like this because it is totally based in the past and does not allow for changed circumstances.
1) It talks about the apparent neutrality of the B of E. I can imagine the time when the B of E comprised a few men in suits and top hats who made decisions based on their viewpoint alone, one which would be different from that of the man in the street (who probably didn’t even know that the B of E existed). Today, newspapers and internet articles are explaining everything and decisions based on neutrality now are for everybody to discuss. This makes the B of E, itself, into a political animal. Every decision it makes is political. When the B of E puts up interest rates, millions of mortgage payers scream and blame the government of the time.
2) Goods and services are now different than they were. After WW2 a decision to release more money into circulation might have resulted in a new factory to make millions of widgets to export to the rest of the world. This new factory might have employed 3000 people, all tax payers, who would have been paying for the NHS and old-age pensions, and the export of the widgets would have allowed us to buy plenty of energy and foreign foodstuffs to improve our lives. Today, new ventures might employ a couple of hundred tax payers, who would make a contribution to our economy but not enough to keep the NHS going properly. In 2023, the UK’s most valuable exports came from gems and precious metal (16.7% of our exports). How many thousands of taxpayers does this industry employ? Are people who make gems more tax-savvy than the man who used to work in a factory? – I suspect they are.
I have to say that I am nervous of economists who quote the thoughts of Hume and Locke. Economics can’t be a science like Physics because I can’t imagine that modern physicists would be quoting Isaac Newton. Therefore it must be an art and a matter of opinion. That is worrying to me.
Any cash released into the economy now simply ends up being stored in housing by the wealthy, pushing it out of reach of hardworking families
Really interesting and thoughtful post but I’m pretty sure that modern physicists quote Newton: calculus, the basic laws of motion and gravity are the same (most of the time).
Why does Reeves have a picture of the founder of the British communist party in her office?
Why after lying on her cv is she still in office?
Does anyone believe her when she says she is an economist?
By talking down the economy while raising taxes has she crashed the economy on purpose?
Isn’t that what communists do? They don’t even mind. It lets them take more control. Do Labour care that everyone is going to get poorer? This is my, very serious, question.
I doubt very much that she is acting alone. Hard not to agree with you that the government seems intent on bringing this country to its knees.
I’m a bit shocked to see so many people on Unherd upticking what are effectively conspiracy theories – and not even very plausible ones at that.
What is your explanation for the bizarre behaviour of nearly all western governments in the past decade or so? They’re clearly not operating in the interests of their electorates.
“Why does Reeves have a picture of the founder of the British communist party in her office?”
Because in heart and mind and to all intents and purposes she is one.
I think Hanlon’s Razor applies in respect of Reeves and the Labour government in general right now: “never ascribe to malice what can be explained by incompetence”.
Reeves might stupidly admire communists and all sorts of other rabble, but it is reasonably clear that she was genuinely amazed that the biggest tax rise in history caused a recessionary effect and drove up Britain’s borrowing costs.
If one wishes to understand the political impact of money supply one need look no further than QE. In the absence.of.more stuff, the excess money simply flowed into assets of all types, increasing the gini co-efficient and the political backlash we now see. Since government’s favourite strategy for dealing with a debt crisis is debasement, more of the same lies in our stars.
The strategies for.dealing with it are usually statism, so winners and losers determined increasingly by government, financial repression, wealth taxes, and in extremis war, the latter often a symptom not.a conscious choice.
We are simply in the lull before these political storms break. It is relatively easy to imagine a circumstance in the UK where a purportedly centrist Labour cabinet.gives way to something harder left. Reeves response to tax shortfalls and burgeoning costs.in Q2 may see a party response.as.newly.elected left wingers find voice. 4th turning theorists have 2027/28 slated.as the high point of this crisis.
Reeves will do what every Chancellor since Brown has done: manipulate the housing market to create more wealth for the suburban voters who decide elections. The productive economy will decline further as a result.
Good post btw. It would be great if more people understood these things.
63% if the UK workforce is now employed in small business. Instead of manipulating the money supply in order to buy the votes of suburban property owners with endlessly rising house prices, a responsible government would take measures to stimulate that sector by legislating for more flexible employment practices, reducing the tax burden on business owners, perhaps providing partial loan guarantees.
Let’s not hold our breath.
High quality analysis, full of tangible examples and good references. I think it shows that the West – not just the UK – is suffering from severe, dogmatic economic thinking. The impact of money creation, private debt and credit are still largely ignored by mainstream economists. Instead, states remain subordinate to these economists and poorly functioning international financial markets. Governments will sing the song of austerity prescribed by these financial markets, unless they themselves are in need of the nanny state for subsidies, bailouts or tax breaks. Politicians seem incapable of changing this status quo, because, indeed, selling off every asset and true expert left the state impotent.
After the financial crisis in 2008 all of these inconsistencies became abundantly clear. But instead of serious reforms and holding those responsible accountable, the status quo doubled down to protect itself. After massive quantitative easing, normal people got the bill in the form of (asset) inflation, e.g. unaffordable housing and ever worsening inequality. These stimuli did not do much to boost and rebuild the real economy, a missed opportunity. Some in the middle class are happy because they already owned a house and think they are wealthy. But it is paper wealth. Moreover, If Piketty is right, the wealth transfer won’t stop. If the return on capital remains higher than economic growth, the ultra-wealthy will out-compete everyone. Even upper middle class families will eventually lose their assets, thus the middle class will simply cease to exist.
I think the article and comments reflects my long held belief that Economics is not a science or indeed a subject of much value. Most so called economists are simply political animals looking for some legitimacy in their views.
A study of common sense would be more useful e.g if you keep borrowing more and more you will find yourself with increasing problems. If your energy prices are very high you will not be able to compete. If your labour costs are very high ( direct wages and indirect costs). If you overtax wealthy people you will end up with a high percentage of less.
Finally if you have people running things who have little practical experience but lots of ideology then this is a recipe for a dysfunctional society and economy.
I’ve never been a fan of BoE independence, it’s anti-demicratic. Back in the day when Ken Clarke and Eddie George decided interest rates between them – rather well as it happens – I could, if I disagreed with their decisions, vote against the Chancellor’s party at the next election. There’s no way I can vote to get rid of Andrew Bailey, more’s the pity.
Seems like a long-winded way of saying theoretical economics doesn’t work in real life and printing biblical quantities of fiat money leads to massive inflation.
Special subject – the bleeding obvious?
I’m no economist but I thought printing more money and putting it into the system was just always a bad idea. A kind of indirect , slow motion theft.
Want growth? Govts must stop promising to do everything for us. Talk up personal responsibility, provide minimal guardrails, then get out if the way.
Stop importing cheap labour, reduce taxes on businesses and raise them considerably on capital gains to discourage the dumping of capital into assets such as housing
you may not be interested in the Bond Market …
One ghost story by the great MR James featured a landscape picture (which would presumably meet with Starmer’s approval) but one night a figure appeared at the edge of the lawn, and the next night it had crawled further across the lawn, until a few nights later it was (shock horror) almost at the front door …
I won’t spoil the surprise, but if Starmer had been in a character in the ghost story and living in the house, the hideous spectre crawling relentlessly across the lawn would be (to him) a horror called Farage, with Reform climbing steadily upwards in the polls!
Edit: Damn, meant to post this in the article on Starmer being haunted!
Before we can even have this interesting discussion (and I very much agree with the author), a state must have a currency. Where dies that leave us?